11.2 Determining Whether an Option for Additional Goods or Services Represents a Material Right
The example below, which is reproduced from ASC 606, illustrates a
contract with an option for additional goods or services that is akin to a marketing
offer and thus does not represent a material right.
ASC 606-10
Example 50 — Option That Does Not Provide
the Customer With a Material Right (Additional Goods or
Services)
55-340 An entity in the
telecommunications industry enters into a contract with a
customer to provide a handset and monthly network service
for two years. The network service includes up to 1,000 call
minutes and 1,500 text messages each month for a fixed
monthly fee. The contract specifies the price for any
additional call minutes or texts that the customer may
choose to purchase in any month. The prices for those
services are equal to their standalone selling prices.
55-341 The entity determines that
the promises to provide the handset and network service are
each separate performance obligations. This is because the
customer can benefit from the handset and network service
either on their own or together with other resources that
are readily available to the customer in accordance with the
criterion in paragraph 606-10-25-19(a). In addition, the
handset and network service are separately identifiable in
accordance with the criterion in paragraph 606-10-25-19(b)
(on the basis of the factors in paragraph 606-10-25-21).
55-342 The entity determines that
the option to purchase the additional call minutes and texts
does not provide a material right that the customer would
not receive without entering into the contract (see
paragraph 606-10-55-43). This is because the prices of the
additional call minutes and texts reflect the standalone
selling prices for those services. Because the option for
additional call minutes and texts does not grant the
customer a material right, the entity concludes it is not a
performance obligation in the contract. Consequently, the
entity does not allocate any of the transaction price to the
option for additional call minutes or texts. The entity will
recognize revenue for the additional call minutes or texts
if and when the entity provides those services.
Once a material right is identified, it must be accounted for as a
performance obligation. However, the identification of material rights has been the
focus of many questions from stakeholders.
In determining whether an option for future goods or services is a
material right, an entity should (1) consider factors outside the current
transaction (e.g., the current class of customer1) and (2) assess both quantitative and qualitative factors. Further, an entity
should also evaluate incentives and programs to understand whether they are customer
options designed to influence customer behavior (i.e., an entity should consider
incentives and programs from the customer’s perspective) because this could be an
indicator that an option is a material right.
For example, regarding certain offers, such as “Buy three, get one
free,” the quantities involved are less important than the fact that an entity would
be “giving away” future sales in such cases. While not determinative, such an
indicator may lead an entity to conclude that a customer option is a material
right.
When determining whether a contract option provides a material
right, entities should consider not only the quantitative significance of the option
(i.e., the quantitative value of the benefit) but also previous and future
transactions with the customer as well as qualitative factors. Specifically,
qualitative features such as whether the rights accumulate (e.g., loyalty points)
are likely to provide a qualitative benefit that may give rise to a material right.
In accordance with ASC 606-10-25-16B, entities should not apply the guidance in ASC
606-10-25-16A on assessing whether promises for immaterial goods or services are
performance obligations to the assessment of whether a contract option provides a
material right (i.e., an optional good offered for free or at a discount, such as
that provided through loyalty point programs, may not be material for an individual
contract but could be material in the aggregate and accounted for as a material
right).
An entity should consider its customer’s reasonable expectations
when identifying promised goods or services. A customer’s perspective on what
constitutes a material right might consider qualitative factors (e.g., whether the
right accumulates). Therefore, a numeric threshold alone might not determine whether
a material right is provided by a customer option in a contract.
Refer to Examples 49 (Section 11.8), 50 (Section 11.2), 51 (Section 11.9), and 52 (Section 11.2.2) in ASC 606-10-55-336 through
55-356 for illustrations of how an entity would determine whether an option provides
a customer with a material right. In addition, some industries, such as the software
industry, more commonly provide customers with options to purchase additional goods
or services. Refer to Sections
12.3.3.1 and 12.6.3.2 for examples of how an entity would assess whether options
to purchase additional copies of software or options to renew postcontract customer
support (PCS) provide a customer with a material right.
The above issue is addressed in Q&As 12 through 14 (compiled
from previously issued TRG Agenda Papers 6, 11, 54, and 55) of the FASB staff’s Revenue Recognition Implementation
Q&As (the “Implementation Q&As”). For additional
information and Deloitte’s summary of issues discussed in the Implementation
Q&As, see Appendix
C.
11.2.1 Need for Assessing Whether a Material Right Exists When the Residual Approach Was Used to Establish the Stand-Alone Selling Price of the Additional Goods or Services
Determining the stand-alone selling price of goods or services
offered to a customer under a contract option is a necessary step in the
assessment of whether a material right exists. The ability to sell certain goods
or services for a wide range of prices may make it difficult to establish the
stand-alone selling price of goods or services offered to a customer under a
contract option (e.g., a renewal option). This is especially true in the
software industry, in which the incremental costs incurred to sell additional
software licenses are often minimal and therefore allow software entities to
sell their software at prices spanning a wide range of discounts or even
premiums. Consequently, the FASB included the residual approach in ASC 606 as a
“suitable” method for establishing the stand-alone selling price.
If an entity applied the residual approach to establish the
stand-alone selling price of goods or services because the stand-alone selling
price of those goods or services is highly variable or uncertain, the entity is
required to assess whether an option (e.g., a renewal option) to acquire more of
those goods or services conveys a material right to the customer. Under ASC
606-10-55-41 through 55-45, a customer option to purchase additional goods or
services gives rise to a material right if the option provides the entity’s
customer with a discount that is incremental to the range of discounts typically
given for those goods or services to that class of customer (e.g., a customer in
a particular geographic area or market). It would not be appropriate for the
entity to conclude that no material right was conveyed to the customer simply
because the stand-alone selling price of the goods or services that are subject
to the option is highly variable or uncertain and the residual approach was
therefore applied.
When the residual approach is used to determine the stand-alone
selling price of a good or service because pricing is highly variable or
uncertain, assessing whether option pricing for that good or service provides a
material right may require significant judgment because of the lack of a point
estimate or sufficiently consistent range representing the stand-alone selling
price. While we believe that entities are likely to identify fewer material
rights in such cases, they are nonetheless required to base their determination
of whether a material right was provided on all reasonably available
information. Although the presence of highly variable or uncertain pricing
complicates the identification of material rights, we believe that when doing
so, an entity should consider (1) the definition of a material right2 and (2) the allocation objective in ASC 606-10-32-28. In other words, an
entity must determine whether the pricing of the optional good or service (1)
indicates that preferential pricing would not have been received “but for” the
initial contract or (2) reflects the amount to which the entity expects to be
entitled in exchange for transferring that good or service to the customer. If
the pricing does not meet the allocation objective (i.e., it is a discount that
is incremental to what other similar customers would receive), a material right
should be identified. We believe that an entity might find the following factors
useful in determining whether a material right is present when the pricing of
optional future purchases is highly variable or uncertain:
-
How the pricing of the optional future purchase aligns with current pricing policies and practices — For example, if a good or service is not typically sold below a certain amount because it is a premium offering, an option to buy the good or service at an amount below that floor would be at odds with standard pricing practices and may therefore convey a material right to the customer.
-
How the pricing of the optional future purchase compares to historical amounts allocated to the good or service in similar situations — Such a comparison is likely to require an entity to look to historical data and stand-alone selling prices that were derived by using the residual approach. Accordingly, while there will not be an established point estimate or narrow range of stand-alone selling prices against which to compare the pricing of the optional future purchase, ASC 606-10-32-34(c) indicates that the residual approach is a method of establishing a stand-alone selling price. Therefore, the amounts determined under that approach represent the stand-alone selling price for that good or service. Consequently, we believe that in assessing whether a customer has been given a material right, an entity may obtain useful information by comparing the pricing of an optional future purchase with historical stand-alone selling prices that were determined as a result of applying the residual approach. In addition, to determine which range of historical stand-alone selling prices to compare with the pricing of the optional future purchase, entities should consider only those transactions that are similar to the transaction in question. For example, an entity might disaggregate historical stand-alone selling price data by one or more of the following characteristics: class of customer, geography, distribution channel, or contract value.
-
How the pricing of the optional future purchase compares to historical contractually stated pricing (if any) of the good or service in similar situations — While the contractually stated pricing may not necessarily represent the stand-alone selling price (see ASC 606-10-32-32), the historical price across a range of different contracts may nevertheless be relevant evidence of an entity’s pricing practices and discounts it may offer on future purchases.
-
Whether the pricing of the optional future purchase is intended to incorporate a discount — If the intent during negotiations was to give the customer a discount on future purchases, a material right may exist since the allocation objective is less likely to be met in such cases. For example, a customer may only have agreed to enter into an initial contract if the vendor offered discounted pricing on future purchases.
-
Whether the pricing of the optional future purchase is discounted relative to (1) the price of similar goods or services sold under the initial contract or (2) the list price when compared with the discounted list prices of all goods or services (whether similar or not) sold under the initial contract — We acknowledge that this factor conflicts with the FASB’s reasons for departing from its definition of a significant incremental discount in legacy GAAP under ASC 985-605. In paragraph BC387 of ASU 2014-09, the Board indicates its rationale for defining “incremental” solely by reference to other comparable transactions:[T]he Boards observed that even if the offered discount is not incremental to other discounts in the contract, it nonetheless could, in some cases, give rise to a material right to the customer. Consequently, the Boards decided not to carry forward that part of the previous revenue recognition guidance from U.S. GAAP into Topic 606.However, we believe that when evaluated in conjunction with all other available evidence, a comparison of the pricing of the optional future purchase with any discounts offered in the initial contract may provide insight into an entity’s pricing practices and discounting intentions. Pricing of the optional future purchase at an amount that is lower than the price under the original contract may indicate the presence of a material right. Conversely, pricing of the optional future purchase at an amount that is lower than the list price but is nevertheless consistent with the discounted price charged under the original contract may be evidence to support a conclusion that the discounted price represents the stand-alone selling price.
-
How the pricing of the optional future purchase aligns with any intended future pricing for similar goods or services — For example, an option to buy add-on software at a set price may not give the customer a material right if that price approximates the amount at which management intends to sell that software on a stand-alone basis in the near future.
-
The relative negotiating power of the entity and the customer — In certain situations, customers may have a greater ability to demand discounted pricing on optional future purchases if the customers represent significantly larger, well-known brands that are dominant in their markets, are more mature, or are otherwise better positioned than the entity selling the goods or services.
The above factors are not intended to be all-inclusive or prescriptive, and each
factor on its own may not be determinative. Entities may need to use significant
judgment when determining whether a material right has been granted. Entities
with highly variable or uncertain pricing should establish a policy for
evaluating material rights and apply that policy consistently in similar
situations.
The examples below demonstrate the application of some of the concepts described
above.
Example 11-1
Entity J, an early-stage software developer, enters into
an arrangement with Customer T, a large U.S.-based
company, to license its software on a term basis and
provide PCS for one year. The arrangement also includes
hardware and professional services. The total
transaction price is $2 million, and J has established
that the license, PCS, hardware, and professional
services each represent a distinct performance
obligation.
Entity J has concluded that the pricing of software
licenses is highly variable and uses the residual
approach to determine the stand-alone selling price. The
observable stand-alone selling prices of the other
performance obligations are as follows:
- PCS — $200,000.
- Professional services — $500,000.
- Hardware — $300,000.
Under the residual approach, $1 million is allocated to
the software license, which J determines is consistent
with the allocation objective. The contract also
indicates that the customer may renew the software
license for $250,000 per additional year and that the
pricing for other products and services will be at their
stand-alone selling prices.
Entity J reviews historical transaction data for sales of
software licenses to large customers in the United
States to determine the amounts that have been allocated
to the software license under the residual approach.
Over the past year, a range of $500,000 to $3 million
has been allocated to the software license, which is
consistent with J’s pricing policies. While J did not
initially intend to give T a discount, it was willing to
negotiate on renewal pricing because it wanted to secure
the large contract and is able to enhance the
marketability of its products by obtaining T as a
customer (T is a well-known brand and dominant in its
market). Therefore, J concludes that the pricing of the
optional future purchase has given T a material
right.
We believe that the following factors indicate that T has
received a material right:
- A comparison of (1) the price T must pay if it exercises its option to renew the license in the future ($250,000) and (2) the range of stand-alone selling prices determined under the residual approach in similar historical transactions ($500,000 to $3 million) indicates that the pricing offered to T does not meet the allocation objective because T is receiving a significant discount that is incremental to the range of discounts offered to other similar customers.
- Although J did not initially intend to give T a discount on future purchases, other facts and circumstances indicate that J nonetheless offered T preferential pricing.
Example 11-2
Entity A enters into an arrangement with
Customer C, a midsized company based in Europe, to
license its software on a term basis and provide PCS for
one year. The arrangement also includes hardware and
professional services. The total transaction price is
$20,000, and A has established that the license, PCS,
hardware, and professional services each represent a
distinct performance obligation.
Entity A has concluded that the pricing of software
licenses is highly variable and uses the residual
approach to determine the stand-alone selling price. It
has observable stand-alone selling prices for its other
products and services. The list price, contractually
stated price, discount from list price, and stand-alone
selling price of each performance obligation are as
follows:
The contract also indicates that the customer may renew
the software license for $3,000 per additional year,
which represents a 60 percent discount from the list
price, and that the pricing for other products and
services remains at the same contractually stated
prices.
Entity A reviews historical transaction
data for sales of software licenses to midsized
customers in Europe to determine the contractually
stated prices and related discounts from list price for
the software license. Over the past year, the software
license has been priced between $1,000 to $20,000, thus
ranging from a discount of 87 percent to a premium of
167 percent relative to the list price. Entity A’s
internal pricing policies require that discounts of over
50 percent must undergo an extensive approval process.
Further, A intended to give C a discount on renewals of
the software license because A is in a highly
competitive market in which customer retention is
difficult. In addition, C indicated that it would
purchase large additional amounts of hardware.
Therefore, A concludes that the pricing of the optional
future purchase(s) gives C a material right.
We believe that the following factors indicate that C has
received a material right:
- It is not especially meaningful to compare (1) the discount to the list price C receives if it exercises its option to renew the license in the future (60 percent) with (2) the range of discounts and premiums in similar historical transactions (87 percent discount to 167 percent premium) given the significant pricing variation observed in the data. However, A’s internal pricing policies require any discounts of over 50 percent undergo an extensive approval process.
- On the basis of a comparison of (1) the discount from list price for the renewal pricing (60 percent) with (2) the other discounts offered in the same contract (0 percent to 38 percent for other goods and services and 40 percent for the same software license), A determines that the optional future purchase pricing conveys an incremental discount to C that it did not receive under the initial contract.
- Entity A’s intention to give C a discount to secure its future business in a competitive market supports a conclusion that “but for the initial contract,” C would not have received favorable pricing on future software license renewals.
- Customer C’s indication that it would make many additional purchases of hardware supports A’s decision to provide preferential pricing.
11.2.2 Loyalty Programs and Accumulation Features
ASC 606-10
Example 52 — Customer Loyalty
Program
55-353 An entity has a
customer loyalty program that rewards a customer with 1
customer loyalty point for every $10 of purchases. Each
point is redeemable for a $1 discount on any future
purchases of the entity’s products. During a reporting
period, customers purchase products for $100,000 and
earn 10,000 points that are redeemable for future
purchases. The consideration is fixed, and the
standalone selling price of the purchased products is
$100,000. The entity expects 9,500 points to be
redeemed. The entity estimates a standalone selling
price of $0.95 per point (totalling $9,500) on the basis
of the likelihood of redemption in accordance with
paragraph 606-10-55-44.
55-354 The points provide a
material right to customers that they would not receive
without entering into a contract. Consequently, the
entity concludes that the promise to provide points to
the customer is a performance obligation. The entity
allocates the transaction price ($100,000) to the
product and the points on a relative standalone selling
price basis as follows:
Product $91,324 [$100,000 × ($100,000
standalone selling price ÷ $109,500)]
Points $8,676 [$100,000 × ($9,500 standalone
selling price ÷ $109,500)]
55-355 At the end of the
first reporting period, 4,500 points have been redeemed,
and the entity continues to expect 9,500 points to be
redeemed in total. The entity recognizes revenue for the
loyalty points of $4,110 [(4,500 points ÷ 9,500 points)
× $8,676] and recognizes a contract liability of $4,566
($8,676 – $ 4,110) for the unredeemed points at the end
of the first reporting period.
55-356 At the end of the
second reporting period, 8,500 points have been redeemed
cumulatively. The entity updates its estimate of the
points that will be redeemed and now expects that 9,700
points will be redeemed. The entity recognizes revenue
for the loyalty points of $3,493 {[(8,500 total points
redeemed ÷ 9,700 total points expected to be redeemed) ×
$8,676 initial allocation] – $4,110 recognized in the
first reporting period}. The contract liability balance
is $1,073 ($8,676 initial allocation – $7,603 of
cumulative revenue recognized).
Loyalty programs allow customers to accumulate points upon each
purchase of goods or services; the points accumulated may then be redeemed to
obtain future goods or services from the same vendor. That is, the customer is
granted an option to purchase additional goods or services by redeeming the
points. Accordingly, ASC 606-10-25-18(j) requires the option to be recognized as
a distinct performance obligation when the option provides the customer with a
material right as defined in ASC 606-10-55-41 through 55-45.
We believe that the existence of an accumulation feature in a
loyalty program is a strong indicator of a material right, to which an entity
would need to allocate a portion of the current contract’s transaction price. We
expect it to be a rare conclusion that loyalty programs with accumulation
features are not material rights.
In circumstances in which a customer’s loyalty points accumulate
with each transaction, the entity should evaluate the current, past, and future
transactions made by the customer in evaluating whether the loyalty program
provides the customer with a material right. In addition, the entity should
consider both qualitative and quantitative factors and, in particular, should
consider whether the material right accumulates over time (after multiple
transactions). That is, the entity should consider factors related to both the
current transaction and the loyalty program in its entirety when analyzing
whether an option provides a material right (and should therefore be accounted
for as a distinct performance obligation in accordance with ASC 606-10-25-18(j)
and ASC 606-10-55-41 through 55-45).
For example, in any given transaction, the number of loyalty points awarded may
not be quantitatively material; however, the structure of the loyalty program
could be designed to influence customer behavior and therefore be a qualitative
indicator that the option provides a material right.
The above issue is addressed in Implementation Q&A 12 (compiled from
previously issued TRG Agenda Papers 6 and 11). For additional information and
Deloitte’s summary of issues discussed in the Implementation Q&As, see
Appendix C.
Note that the above discussion focuses on loyalty programs in which points that a
customer has earned by purchasing goods or services from a vendor are redeemed
for future goods or services from the same vendor. For loyalty programs in which
accumulated points can be redeemed for goods or services from a third party or
for goods or services from the original vendor that meet the requirement to be a
separate performance obligation, the original vendor should evaluate upon
redemption whether it is acting as a principal or as an agent in the transaction
associated with the deferred recognition of revenue. (See Chapter 10 for additional considerations related
to the assessment of whether an entity is a principal or an agent.) For example,
suppose that Company X, an airline, offers one point for every $100 a customer
spends. The accumulated points can be redeemed for either future flights
provided by X or future hotel stays with Hotel Y, a vendor with which X has
partnered. Since X has determined that its loyalty programs offer a material
right that is a performance obligation, X defers a portion of revenue for the
redemption of the loyalty points. Upon a customer’s redemption of points for
either a flight or a hotel stay, X evaluates whether it is acting as a principal
or as an agent in that transaction.
Further, any changes to an entity’s incentives (e.g., loyalty programs, rebates,
method of redeeming points, amounts for which points are earned) should be
evaluated under the contract modification guidance discussed in Chapter 9.
11.2.3 Considering the Class of Customer in the Evaluation of Whether a Customer Option Gives Rise to a Material Right
As noted in Section
11.2.2, when determining whether a material right exists, an entity
should take into account past, current, and future transactions as well as both
qualitative and quantitative factors (including whether the right
accumulates).
ASC 606-10-55-42 states, in part, that an “option gives rise to
a performance obligation in the contract only if the option provides a material
right to the customer that it would not receive without entering into that
contract (for example, a discount that is incremental to the range of discounts
typically given for those goods or services to that class of customer in that
geographic area or market).”
Stakeholder views have differed regarding how the class of
customer should be considered in an entity’s evaluation of whether a customer
option gives rise to a material right. Implementation Q&A 14 (compiled from
previously issued TRG Agenda Papers 54 and 55) and TRG Agenda Paper 54 provide the
following examples of the FASB staff’s views on this topic:
Example
|
Facts
|
FASB Staff Analysis and Views
|
---|---|---|
Volume discounts
|
|
Company A will need to consider all
relevant facts and circumstances (including the price
charged to other high-volume customers) to determine
whether the price offered in year 2 represents the
stand-alone selling price for the part. Said
differently, A would need to determine whether the
discount (1) is incremental to the discount that would
be offered to other similar customers (such as that
offered to C) and (2) would be offered to a similar
customer independently of any prior contract the
customer had with A. Company A would not consider
pricing offered to other customers that is contingent on
prior-year volume purchases.
Pricing offered to B that is comparable
to pricing offered to other similar customers (and is
offered independently of prior contracts with A) may be
an indication that there is no incremental discount and
therefore no material right. However, pricing that is
not comparable may be an indication that a material
right has been given to B because B has prepaid for
parts in year 2.
|
Tier status
|
|
The airline needs to evaluate whether
the ticket purchase (the contract) includes a material
right by determining whether the customer’s option to
receive discounted goods (e.g., a free checked bag) is
independent of the current contract with the customer.
In other words, the airline would need to consider
whether the benefits (e.g., discounts) given under a
tier status program are incremental to discounts given
to a similar class of customer who did not enter into a
prior contract with the airline. In performing the
evaluation, the company could:
The airline would not consider the price
charged to other customers who received status benefits
through prior contracts with the airline since doing so
would not help it determine whether such discounted
pricing is offered independently of the current
contract.
|
The FASB staff noted that an entity will be required to use
significant judgment to determine whether a material right is provided to the
entity’s customers. Further, the staff noted that it “is not in a position to
reach broad conclusions about these types of fact patterns because there are
many variations of contracts and variations in facts and circumstances that can
affect the conclusion in each fact pattern.”3 However, the staff emphasized the following:
-
The relative importance placed on the considerations discussed in the examples (or other considerations) will vary on the basis of an entity’s facts and circumstances.
-
The objective of the guidance in ASC 606-10-55-42 and 55-43 is to determine whether a customer option to receive discounted goods is independent of an existing contract with a customer.
TRG members debated the application of concepts in the framework
the staff used to analyze the examples in Implementation Q&A 14 and TRG
Agenda Paper 54 but did not reach general agreement on (1) how or when to
consider past transactions in determining the class of customer and (2) how the
class of customer should be evaluated in the determination of the stand-alone
selling price of an optional good or service.
A few TRG members maintained that discounts or status achieved
through past transactions is akin to accumulating features in loyalty programs
(and that such features therefore represent material rights). However, others
indicated that these programs represent marketing inducements (i.e., discounts)
for future transactions that should be evaluated in relation to those offered to
other similar customers or potential customers (e.g., other high-volume
customers or potential high-volume customers). The TRG members who viewed the
programs as marketing inducements believed that considering a customer’s past
transactions, among other factors, is appropriate in the evaluation of whether a
good or service being offered to the customer reflects the stand-alone selling
price for that class of customer in accordance with ASC 606-10-55-42
(particularly for entities that have limited alternative sources of information
available upon which to establish a customer’s class). Further, these TRG
members focused on the facts that (1) similar discounts on future transactions
(like those provided in the form of benefits and other offers in status programs
for no additional fees) may be given to other customers who did not make or have
the same level of prior purchases with the entity and (2) such discounts may be
provided at the stand-alone selling price for that class of customer (i.e., the
good or service is not priced at a discount that is incremental to the range of
discounts typically offered to that class of customer and therefore do not
represent a material right).
Following its stakeholder outreach, the FASB staff indicated
that an entity should evaluate whether tier status programs contain material
rights or represent a marketing incentive. In making this evaluation, the FASB
staff indicated that entities should consider whether discounts offered on
future goods or services to customers within a given tier of a status program
are incremental to the range of discounts typically given to that class of
customer. If an entity never provides customers with tier status other than
through past purchases, the discounts provided to customers under the program
are likely to be material rights. However, if an entity sometimes provides tier
status to customers for reasons other than past purchases, the discounts may be
marketing incentives provided to a particular class of customer. The
determination of whether discounts under a tier status program are material
rights or marketing incentives will require judgment based on an evaluation of
the specific facts and circumstances of the specific program.
Footnotes
1
ASC 606-10-25-2 and ASC 606-10-55-42.
2
A material right arises from pricing on an option to
acquire additional goods or services in the future that would not have
been received if the initial contract had not been entered into. In such
cases, the customer with the option has essentially prepaid for the
future purchase.
3
Quoted from Implementation Q&A 14.